Venezuela: Conservative Representation Without Conservative Parties
Why would a powerful elite ever consent to government of the people, by the people, and
for the people? Democratic institutions would soon encroach on the interests of the privileged
few if political equality were fully enforced. This dilemma is especially central to the study of
democracy in Latin America, where social and economic inequality are so great that economic
elites are often threatened by pressure to share their wealth,(1) and often have sufficient political
resources to respond by having democratic governments removed. For this reason political
scientists have long held that democratic regimes are more likely to survive where there are
guarantees that the fundamental interests of economic elites--and any other powerful minorities--will be protected.(2) There is no better illustration of the crucial role played by accommodation of
elite interests than Venezuela's transition to democracy in 1958. Business leaders intervened
against the military and on behalf of democracy at key moments because a series of pacts, in
Terry Karl's (and Barrington Moore's) words, "represented a classic exchange, primarily
between AD and the entrepreneurs, of 'the right to rule for the right to make money.'"(3)
Recently some scholars have proposed that elite interests are best protected, and
democracy best preserved, by successful conservative parties. Regarding successful democratic
transitions, for example, O'Donnell and Schmitter wrote:
Parties of the Right-Center and Right must be "helped" to do well. . . . The problem is
especially acute for those partisan forces representing the interests of propertied classes,
privileged professionals, and entrenched institutions. . . . Unless their party or parties can
muster enough votes to stay in the game, they are likely to desert the electoral process in
favor of antidemocratic conspiracy and destabilization.(4)
Although conservative parties can provide the guarantees elites want, there is no reason to limit
our attention to representation through the formal channel of party competition and elections.
All that really matters for democratic stability is that economic elites feel secure; it does not
matter whether this feeling comes from one conservative party, several conservative parties,
conservative factions inside all parties, personal ties to individual leaders, or confidence in the
efficacy of bribery and intimidation, as long as the regime is otherwise democratic. The degree
to which these informal channels of representation create feelings of security may well depend
on the nature of the parties, but the relevant aspect of their nature could be how pragmatic they
are, how large, how fractionalized, how disciplined, how homogeneous, or how corrupt, rather
than how far to the left or the right.(5)
Venezuela has not had any significant parties since 1958 that were uncontestably
conservative.(6) Instead, during the first thirty years of its democratic regime, Venezuela
developed effective ways of representing elite interests informally, centered around clientelistic
relationships between individual politicians and family-owned economic groups. This
arrangement was possible because the two main parties, Acción Democrática (AD) and COPEI,
were large, powerful, ideologically heterogeneous, factionalized, and thoroughly pragmatic, and
because the oil wealth flowing through the state created a prolonged positive-sum game that
encouraged consensus. For decades these informal arrangements enhanced political stability.
But they had unhealthy side effects--corruption and inefficiency--which grew increasingly
worse, so that when the economic decline began in 1979 and the abuses became widely known,
Venezuela entered a period of political instability. The violent popular reaction against Carlos
Andrés Pérez's economic shock program in 1989 and the two coup attempts in 1992 were only
very indirectly related to these clientelistic practices. But the parties' reactions to the instability,
as well as to their unprecedented defeats in the 1993 and 1997 elections, opened a dangerous rift
between the parties and the private sector.
No Significant Clearly Conservative Parties
The controversial assertion that there are no significant conservative parties in Venezuela
requires some explanation. Many Venezuelans and outside observers consider the Social
Christian Party COPEI a conservative party. After all, in the 1940s it received support from
business elites and advocates of dictatorship and had close ties to the conservative Church
hierarchy, which celebrated the overthrow of Rómulo Gallegos in 1948;(7) in 1959-63 its presence
in Rómulo Betancourt's government of national unity was reassuring to business leaders;(8) and its
progenitors praised corporatist notions reminiscent of fascism and Francoism.(9) In the 1958
campaign an Unión Republicana Democrática (URD) leader once gave a speech on "Calderismo
y Falangismo."(10) And even in 1985, when I asked 53 AD deputies and senators to locate COPEI
on a 1-10 left-right scale, 85 percent placed it between 8 and 10!(11)
Few of COPEI's leaders would locate themselves so far to the right, today or at any time
in the last 35 years. COPEI is best understood as a Christian Democratic party. Even though
COPEI was never a confessional party, its founders were always motivated primarily by their
Catholic identity. Rafael Caldera, who was always preeminent among these leaders until he left
the party in 1993, had been active in Catholic Action in his teens and attended Catholic Action
conferences at the Vatican and the University of Notre Dame. The first precursor of COPEI was
the Unión Nacional de Estudiantes (UNE), which split away from the Federación de Estudiantes
de Venezuela (FEV) in 1936 when the leftist FEV leadership called for the expulsion of the
Jesuits and other anticlerical reforms. The founders of UNE contested local Caracas elections in
the early 1940s as "Acción Electoral" and "Acción Nacional" before reorganizing as the Comité
de Organización Política Electoral Independiente three months after AD and a military faction
seized power in October 1945. COPEI's first statement of principles dwelt at length on ideas
borrowed from the social teaching of the papal encyclical Quadragesimo Anno (1931), which
reversed the reactionary stance of 1891's Rerum Novarum by embracing democracy, pluralism,
and moderate social reform.
Because COPEI's primary identity is religious, it has never been simple to categorize in
left-right terms. The religious-secular cleavage has cross-cut the left-right cleavage at an ever
more perpendicular angle during the 20th century. That is, in the 19th century, defenders of the
Church were always quite conservative; by the 1920s, some were more reformist on the social
question while others remained reactionary; and by the mid-1960s these conservatives and
reformists often shared the religious side of the cleavage with revolutionaries of the Christian
left. In COPEI's case most of the founding leaders favored the moderate reformism that was
considered progressive in Catholic circles in the 1940s and 50s, but a few founders were clearly
more right-wing, such as Pedro José Lara Peña, who urged Acción Nacional to endorse former
dictator López Contreras for president in 1945.(12) Later on, COPEI developed tendencies farther
to the left, hence the name of its youth wing: Juventud Revolucionaria Copeyana. Although the
party was largely unaffected by liberation theology, there was a definite leftist faction in the
1960s called the astronautas, whose leaders, most notably Abdón Vivas Terán, are still
considered progressive today.(13)
It is true that COPEI has consistently been an anticommunist party, but this opposition
was always directed as much against the materialism and atheism of communism as against its
revolutionary program. Besides, Christian democratic thought has its own reservations about
capitalism and the unbridled play of market forces. COPEI's ideology justifies limiting private
property rights to ensure that property is used for some social benefit, and defends the notion of
a common good, which takes precedence over private interests and is legitimately interpreted
and promoted by the state to allow citizens to realize their full potential. While these positions
are certainly to the right of communism, they are not as far to the right as the orthodoxy of the
IMF and the World Bank. But again, the point is that these positions were developed to locate
the party on the religious-secular dimension, and therefore have no straightforward implications
for its left-right position. Consequently, COPEI's official ideology allows the party to welcome
support from people who may diverge greatly in left-right terms but share a commitment to
religious guidance in public life.
It is also true that COPEI's leaders were rather slow to make a firm commitment to
political democracy as the only legitimate form of government. Rafael Caldera began his
professional career as Sub-Director of the Ministry of Labor (at the age of 21!) in the
dictatorship of General López Contreras from 1936 to 1938.(14) UNE escaped repression under
López Contreras by splitting away from the FEV and taking pains to emphasize that it was just a
student union, not a political party; in fact, its statutes prohibited its leaders from being national
or state leaders of any political party.(15) When these same leaders founded COPEI in 1946, their
goal was to organize a party to ensure that the AD-led October 18 Revolution would fulfill its
promises of democracy and social reform. Caldera himself served as Attorney General during
the first six months of the Revolutionary Junta. But because the country was polarized at the
time between the supporters and opponents of Acción Democrática, COPEI soon became the
chief vehicle for all types of protest against AD. And because the Trienio government was pro-democracy (although not initially democratic), stridently reformist, and anticlerical, COPEI's
supporters included not only defenders of the Church, but also opponents of social reform and
enemies of democracy. Later Copeyanos have tried to distance themselves from these groups as
though they were never really in the party at all. But it would be closer to the truth to say that
COPEI developed a very prominent right wing in its early years, and that even its more reformist
founding leaders felt threatened by the arrogant and partisan AD government and shed few tears
when it fell. Even while professing allegiance to the ideals of the October Revolution and
claiming not to have participated in the coup of 1948, COPEI offered to collaborate with the
new junta to restore political order, but without explicitly calling for a democratic regime:
Now that the new provisional government is constituted, we believe it is our duty to
offer, without ambition for public office, everything necessary to help the country return
to normality, to lead to the pacification of spirits, to impede the development of
conflictual situations that would delay the definitive implantation of an institutional
organization.(16)
It was the dictatorial rule of 1948-58 that made committed democrats out of the
Copeyanos. In 1950, after some COPEI militants had been imprisoned and an AD leader and a
member of the junta itself had been assassinated, COPEI changed its official position from
"Collaboration to Restore Social Peace" to "Critical Expectancy," but still ran Caldera for
president in 1952. However, when junta president Lt. Col. Marcos Pérez Jiménez set aside the
election results and assumed dictatorial power for himself, COPEI finally called for "respect for
the popular will as manifested in the ballot box, because it is convinced that that is the only point
of departure for a solid institutional order."(17) At this point the party lost most of its far right
wing.
COPEI has remained democratic and reformist from 1952 to the present. Caldera signed
the Common Minimum Program in 1958, which committed COPEI to an ambitious land reform
and other progressive measures. During his 1969-74 presidency, Caldera promoted state
planning, continued import substitution industrialization, and supported eventual nationalization
of the foreign-owned oil companies. Although Caldera left COPEI to run as an independent
candidate for president in 1993, his positions were still representative of those of many
Copeyanos, and were little changed from his positions of 25 years earlier. As the author of a
populist labor law, a defender of subsidized gasoline prices and exchange controls, and an
obstacle to privatization and decentralization, Caldera became a symbol of resistance to
economic liberalization. His two most trusted ministers were Luis Raúl Matos Azócar, a former
Adeco with strong socialist leanings, and Teodoro Petkoff, a former Communist guerrilla who
helped found the Movimiento al Socialismo (MAS). It is difficult to reconcile this record with
any criteria for a party of the right.(18) True, Caldera acquiesced in Petkoff's "Venezuela Agenda"
shock program in April 1996, but it was an about-face for both of them that was just as startling
as similar policy switches by social democratic leaders in other countries. At most, COPEI is
very broadly a center-right party, although some of its leaders and positions have been left of
center, and a classification limited to left-right positions misses the religious dimension of the
the party's program and image.
If COPEI is not a party of the right, would some other party qualify? The most obvious
candidate is the Cruzada Cívica Nacionalista (CCN), which was the vehicle of Marcos Pérez
Jiménez in 1968 and won nearly 11 percent of the vote. Some object that this party had no
ideology other than support for the former dictator, who at any rate had some aspirations of
becoming a populist dictator in the mold of Juan Perón or Colombia's Rojas Pinilla. The CCN
subsequently contested several elections without the endorsement of Pérez Jiménez, but quickly
degenerated into an opportunistic microparty. There have been other small parties with a
conservative aura that are probably better classified as personalist, such as Nueva Generación
Democrática (1983-93) and Opinión Nacional (OPINA, 1968-93). The best candidate for a
Venezuelan conservative party is the Frente Nacional Democrático (FND), led by businessmen
and some former officials in the authoritarian government of General Isaías Medina Angarita
(1941-45), among whom Arturo Uslar Pietri is the best known. Uslar ran for president in 1963
and came in fourth with 16 percent of the vote, backed by a coalition called Independientes Pro-Frente Nacional. Without Uslar as a candidate, the FND won only 2.61 percent in 1968 and .25
percent in 1973, and subsequently disappeared. The Movimiento de Acción Nacional (1963-73),
led by journalist Germán Borregales, was also usually considered a right-wing party but was
more personalistic than the FND, and even less successful.(19) The ultimate reason for the
electoral failure of conservative parties is probably that few Venezuelans want to vote for them.
An expert-validated classification of parties in 11 Latin American countries supports this: the
mean left-right tendency in Venezuela has consistently been left- or center-left leaning in all its
democratic elections. None of the other countries has had a tendency this consistent. This does
not mean that the left is particularly strong in Venezuela; only that the center-left has been
strong, and the right and center-right comparatively weak.(20) The few conservative parties in
Venezuela therefore have been rather personalistic, unsuccessful, or short-lived, and usually all
three, which is sufficient reason for considering them insignificant.
To complicate matters further, in some ways Acción Democrática could be accused of
being a center-right party because (1) it has always been passionately anticommunist; (2) it took
responsibility for the violent repression of the guerrilla movements of the 1960s; (3) although it
has a large base of support in organized labor, the union leaders regularly defer to party
leadership, which many times has meant calling off strikes and restraining demands;(21) (4) some
AD leaders have close ties to certain business leaders. Despite these qualifiers, most observers
would call AD a center-left party at least until 1989 because of its historic support for the
expansion of state production and state regulation, its periodic interventions on behalf of the
working class, the precipitous nationalization of the steel and oil industries in 1975-76 by Carlos
Andrés Pérez, and its general support for ISI until very recently. But what is to be made of the
fact that Pérez initiated a shock program of economic liberalization in his second presidency; or
the fact that AD's 1993 presidential candidate, Claudio Fermín, ran on a model economic
liberalization platform? The more closely one examines the records of any of these parties, the
less clear it is where they belong on a left-right spectrum.
Reverse Clientelism
One way to make sense of these inconsistencies and contradictions is to recognize that AD and COPEI are ideologically diverse: each spans a range of positions from the center-left to the center-right or right. A picture of the frequency distributions of each party's leaders on the ideological spectrum would look like overlapping bell curves. The midpoint of AD's curve would be slightly to the left of center, while COPEI's would be slightly to the right.(22) At a very general level of analysis, it makes sense to call AD center-left and COPEI center-right. Figure 1 displays the evolution of the major blocs of parties in Venezuela as defined in this general way. According to this figure, Venezuela has always had significant representation of the Right or Center-Right. (The "Center-Right" basically reflects the vote for COPEI.)
But such general characterizations are not very useful for predicting which policies each
party will support, because much depends on which leader is making policy. While most of
COPEI is to the right of most of AD, there are many prominent AD leaders who are to the right
of Caldera or Luis Herrera Campíns (president from 1979 to 1984), such as Claudio Fermín
(1993 presidential candidate) or Carmelo Lauría (Minister of the Presidency under Carlos
Andrés Pérez in his second term).
The centrism and internal diversity of the two main parties in the seventies and eighties
made it risky for economic elites to throw all their support behind one party, for two reasons.
First, if they backed the wrong party, they would lack access after the elections. But second,
even if "their" party won, important policy decisions could still be made by one of the party
leaders unsympathetic to elite interests. If formal representation through a conservative party
were as important for democratic stability as some have claimed, Venezuela's party system of
the seventies and eighties would have to be considered dysfunctional. But Venezuelan parties
and economic elites developed informal channels of representation that compensated for the
absence of a significant conservative party. In some ways the informal practices described
below enhanced governability, especially in the short and medium terms. But in other ways they
contributed to the fragility of Venezuelan democracy in the 1990s.
One important informal channel was tráfico de influencias, or influence peddling.
Individual politicians accepted cash, goods, and services from certain firms or conglomerates
and in exchange offered their business patrons influence over appointments, legislation, or
policy implementation. It is fitting to call these politician-conglomerate relationships reverse
clientelism. They were like clientelism in that they consisted of voluntary but asymmetrical
face-to-face relationships between two people. It was "reverse" clientelism because unlike the
usual clientelism, in which patrons exchange material favors for political support, politicians
exchanged political favors for material support. Venezuelans increasingly consider this practice
corrupt.(23)
Although much of the evidence for reverse clientelism is circumstantial or anecdotal, it is
common knowledge in Venezuela.(24) In my own fieldwork interviewing AD deputies, senators,
and labor leaders I encountered many politicians who lived beyond their visible means of
financial support. For example, national deputies in 1985 earned a salary of roughly US$20,000
and were prohibited from practicing law or similar professions while serving in congress. The
party itself paid no salary to its leaders. Most came from middle- or lower-class backgrounds;
very few were independently wealthy. Those from the interior collected travel and per diem that
was merely adequate to cover their frequent trips to the capital for legislative sessions. Many of
the deputies I interviewed appeared to be living more or less honestly within these constraints.
But there were several--especially those holding or seeking party office--who somehow could
afford a suite of offices in a respectable building, salaries for 2 or 3 aides and a
chauffeur/bodyguard, and frequent travel to regional party headquarters all over the country.
These leaders usually were reluctant to talk about the source of their financing, but two in
particular admitted that they had a corporate "patron" who provided financial backing for their
political ambitions.(25) Another party leader revealed that the private jet he used while
campaigning was on extended loan from a wealthy businessman. The more ambitious
politicians were more commonly involved in this sort of influence peddling because they were
the ones who both needed the most funding for their political campaigns, and were in the best
position to grant favors.
Political connections were crucial to success in Venezuelan business. This was in large
part due to the power of the large and interventionist state. Antonio Francés described this
aspect of the business environment well:
The Venezuelan firm feels the presence of the state at practically every step. In order to
establish an industry, sign a collective contract, import materials, or export his products,
the entrepreneur must obtain official permits and complete paperwork that is sometimes
very complex and costly. From the state the entrepreneur requests, and often obtains,
purchase orders for his products, credits to expand his plant, subsidies to boost
consumption, construction of infrastructure, the supply of all kinds of public services,
and inputs for his production manufactured by enterprises belonging to the state. The
entrepreneur fears official intervention, the denial of import or export licenses, price
controls at barely profitable levels, supply shortages, and the reduction of import tariffs
that protect his market. The entrepreneur secretly hopes that the state will act as his
safety net [fiador de último recurso], saving him in case of bankruptcy, and keeping the
workers of the enterprise off the street. The state has been for Venezuelan private
enterprise that extravagant, irascible, somewhat unpredictible, but easily influenced
[influenciable] and soft-hearted father, whose magnanimity one can count on in spite of
everything.(26)
Some say that the Venezuelan state has always played this powerful role because of the
country's small oligopolistic economy and dictatorial past.(27) Others claim that it is a more recent
product of the oil economy.(28) Still others would say that Venezuela was typical of a general
Latin American pattern inherited from colonial mercantilism.(29) But whatever the causes were,
the important questions here are how firms coped with this large interventionist state and how
their strategies were affected by the nature of the political parties.
Reverse clientelism developed due to the simple operation of supply and demand:
businesses needed political connections, and politicians needed funding for their campaigns. To
be sure, politicians who controlled the spoils of office were less in need of funding, because the
state provided abundant resources that were easily diverted for partisan or factional purposes.
And state resources were preferred because they came with fewer strings attached, and more
specifically, fewer strings that might prove embarrassing to a politician with a reformist image.
For this reason, I suspect that these patron-client relations between economic elites and
individual politicians were more common in the opposition party and in the "Out" faction of the
governing party.(30) They therefore represented not so much a direct purchase of immediate
influence, as a hedge against the risk of future exclusion. Acting as the patron of a rising party
leader was simply a way to reduce the uncertainty in a very risky and political business
environment.
If the gamble paid off, the payoff could be huge. The patron of the president could
expect privileged access on general policy questions; small regulatory favors such as import
licenses and tax breaks; diplomatic appointments; exclusive bids on lucrative state contracts; and
sometimes the ability to designate trusted associates to fill a few seats in congress or a powerful
cabinet post, such as Finance Minister. Many of these conglomerates--especially those with
nonhispanic names--began as import-export firms long ago, profited handsomely from the
explosion of consumer spending that accomplanied the rapidly growing oil economy, and then
diversified into banking, services, and light manufacturing. At first, presidents named ministers
from among the managers of the holding companies owned by traditionally powerful families
such as Mendoza, Vollmer, Boulton, Phelps, Blohm, and Delfino.(31) Table 1 is a partial listing of
ministers whose prior professional experience was in business rather than in party politics.(32)
In the 1970s, however, Carlos Andrés Pérez set out to raise a new group of lesser
entrepreneurs called the "Twelve Apostles" to great wealth--and possibly greater political
reliability--with virtually unlimited state assistance.(33) Pérez used the huge windfall of
petrodollars from the first OPEC oil shock to finance an ambitious expansion of heavy industry
and infrastructure, which also stimulated private firms in construction, cement, finance, and
other accessories to the state-owned sector. The convictions of former President Jaime Lusinchi
(1984-89) and his former mistress, Blanca Ibáñez, for their dealings with shady businessmen
indicate that at least one president tried to follow in Pérez's footsteps, although on a smaller
scale. Partly as a result of this selective stimulus, the number of important grupos económicos
has multiplied in the last twenty years.
The pragmatism of AD and COPEI helped make reverse clientelism possible. Neither
party was especially rigid in its programs after 1958. Both aimed at the general goals of creating
jobs, promoting nontraditional industry, improving the infrastructure, and raising the standard of
living, but neither had any firm commitments to specific means to any of these ends. The
parties' openness to many development strategies made it easy for individual party leaders to
take whatever self-serving policy a patron wanted and justify it within the broad lines of party
doctrine.
Factions in AD and COPEI were equally pragmatic. During each presidential term, the
supporters of the president in the governing party would form a faction of "Ins," while the more
marginal leaders who were more concerned about choosing a winning presidential candidate for
the next term would form a faction of "Outs." These factions would struggle for control of the
party and the right to nominate the next candidate, but their struggles were devoid of issues with
any economic or social content.(34) This feature of the parties made ties to individual party leaders
not only possible, but necessary, because an economic group would have no confidence that the
party would choose an ideologically sympathetic candidate, and there were no factions to
support that had any reliable left-right position, either. The most reliable actors to support were
therefore individual leaders.
Why Venezuela Should Not Be Considered Corporatist
Some scholars contend that Venezuela either was or increasingly was becoming a
societal corporatist system until the 1980s, with formal representation of peak associations of
labor and capital on numerous policymaking boards.(35) There were, in fact, numerous state
boards and commissions whose charters stipulated that certain of their board members were to
be appointed by the Confederación de Trabajadores de Venezuela (CTV) and one of the business
associations, usually the Federación de Cámaras de Comercio y Producción (FEDECAMARAS),
which is the largest and oldest one. The state delegated to these boards the authority to set
official consumer prices, allocate foreign exchange, and make other important regulatory
decisions. If these boards were autonomous and made authoritative, final decisions, then one
would have to conclude that the main channel for private sector representation was this formal
corporatist channel, not the informal channels emphasized above. This conclusion would imply
that corporatism is the best explanation for any degree of security that economic elites felt in the
absence of a significant conservative party.
I continue to insist on the greater importance of the informal channels for three reasons.(36)
First, most of these state boards and commissions were not well institutionalized. That is, they
were created by one government but abandoned by the next, or were dismantled or overridden
when they tried to make important decisions, or simply never functioned after being authorized
by law.(37) Second, business leaders had little reason to be reassured by its representation in these
bodies because they were almost always tripartite (labor-business-government) boards in which
business representatives were in the minority. During AD governments (all of the governments
from 1996 to 1993 with the exception of Luis Herrera from 1979-84) this lineup could not have
been reassuring to business because the CTV was dominated by AD and frequently deferred to
its leadership, so any tripartite commission was stacked in AD's favor. If AD government
appointees sided with business against labor, it would have been because of informal ties outside
the commission.
The final reason for skepticism about the relevance of corporatist representation is that it
is doubtful that FEDECAMARAS' delegates were very representative of the peak association
that appointed them. FEDECAMARAS has always found it difficult to unite its members
behind a common position. On the one hand, there is a deep division between the very large
firms, which are better able to compete and adapt and are accustomed to having their way, and
the medium-sized and small firms. On the other hand, there are intense rivalries among the large
firms, which have a long history of competing aggressively with one another for shares of the
same small market. Rather than submit to the outcome of negotiations among official
representatives of the state, labor, and an amorphous conglomeration of business interests, the
large firms preferred to minimize the importance of the formal process while continuing to cut
customized deals for themselves directly with the state:
Such a context of highly personalized, informal, ad-hoc, and often illicit, transactions
between businesses and individuals working for the state significantly shaped and
constrained the development of institutionalized forms of business representation. . . .
Institutions created to formally represent business faced great difficulty in providing their
individual members with more profitable government representation services than those
they could muster on their own. Furthermore, the fragmented and oligopolistic structure
of the business sector has made it difficult to articulate under a common institutional
setting the interests of different sectors and even different companies. . . . The owners
and top managers, in whom the real decision power of the company rested, concentrated
on direct and personalized dealings with politicians and high-level bureaucrats. Active
participation in the institutional activities of the affiliated chamber was often delegated to
middle ranking managers--usually former government officials who had little power or
influence in the firm.(38)
This pattern of private-sector representation is strikingly similar to that found in Mexico during
the same period.(39)
How, exactly, did reverse clientelism enhance governability in the short and medium
terms? Particularistic business-party ties should have inspired resentment rather than
contentment because they necessarily gave privileged state access to a few firms while
discriminating against the rest. Economic elites remained loyal to the democratic regime in spite
of the access of the few privileged firms, not because of it. In order to account for the
continuing loyalty of the excluded, one would have to appeal to non-party factors such as the
negotiation of a rough policy consensus during the transition in 1958 and the state's ability to
"buy" support from all important groups with its oil wealth.
But reverse clientelism did enhance stability in a different way: by keeping the economic
elite divided and conquered. Business leaders were not happy about their relationship with the
state. In fact, they grumbled about it in public for decades. If they had grumbled en masse, as a
solid bloc, it would have been a serious blow to the regime. The reason they never did this was
because they all believed that their interests were best served by maintaining their personal
political connections. Reverse clientelism, like clientelism at the grass roots, discouraged clients
from organizing horizontally to achieve common ends.
Representation of Economic Elites After 1979
In 1979 Venezuela entered a long period of economic decline in which real wages fell
below the level they had reached in 1976 and never recovered. In this economic environment
some economic and political leaders questioned the consensus on oil-financed state-led
development that Venezuela had been following for more than 20 years, and a few concluded
that some sort of economic liberalization was necessary to restore economic stability and
growth. In the elections of 1988 and 1993, the two main parties consistently ran candidates who
favored economic liberalization, but they ran into a wall of massive public opposition.
Following their unprecedented defeat in 1993, both parties adapted to the political environment
by marginalizing leaders who favored economic liberalization. This ushered in a period from
1994 to 1998 in which the increasingly united conservative interests had no effective channels of
representation. The rest of this chapter describes the development of this dangerous tension in
party-business relations in four phases corresponding to the governments of Jaime Lusinchi (AD,
1984-89), Carlos Andrés Pérez (AD, 1989-93), Rafael Caldera (independent, 1994-present), and
Hugo Chávez Frías (independent elected in 1998).
The Lusinchi Government
Venezuela's economic problems began, ironically, during the oil boom of the mid-1970s,
when Carlos Andrés Pérez squandered the windfall of petrodollars in a mind-boggling orgy of
free spending and irresponsible borrowing. By the late 1970s, unchecked deficit spending
caused the annual inflation rate to creep up from less than five percent to 20 percent in 1979.
The next president, Luis Herrera Campíns of COPEI, began his administration with an attempt at
fiscal restraint, but in the second oil boom of 1980-81 he abandoned austerity and led the
government to spend and borrow lavishly once again. The cost of these seven years of
mismanagement were magnified in 1982 when the debt crisis hit all of Latin America, raising
the cost of servicing Venezuela's $35 billion debt while cutting off most foreign investment and
lending. This problem was compounded for Venezuela because oil prices began falling at the
same time, and kept falling until 1986, leaving the country with less and less hard currency to
meet its international obligations.
Conflict between Central Bank President Leopoldo Díaz Bruzual and Finance Minister
Julio Sosa paralyzed the government in the face of this looming financial catastrophe. Business
confidence evaporated, and capital flight accelerated. Finally, on February 18, 1983, Díaz
Bruzual devalued the Bolívar by nearly 40 percent and established the Régimen de Cambios
Diferenciales (RECADI) to administer exchange controls. This was an extremely traumatic
event for middle-class Venezuelans, who over the decades had grown accustomed to cheap
imports and affordable vacations in the U.S. and Europe made possible by a very overvalued
exchange rate. The day of the devaluation was dubbed "Black Friday," and it meant that the
good life was over.
Jaime Lusinchi's 1983 landslide restored AD to power in the wake of the unpopular
Herrera administration. Lusinchi took office talking about austerity, and he did slow the
increase in public spending and borrowing, eliminate a few subsidies, and eventually renegotiate
the debt, but he never attempted the kind of privatization or sweeping liberalization of trade,
interest rates, prices, and foreign exchange that was being initiated by his contemporaries in
Chile, Mexico, and Bolivia. The fundamental problems in the Venezuelan economy therefore
went unaddressed during the Lusinchi government, and in the meantime oil prices continued to
fall. By his last year in office, inflation had surpassed 30 percent--the highest rate in Venezuela
since the turn of the century.
In the steadily worsening economic environment of the Herrera and Lusinchi
governments, a division developed in the private sector that would soon challenge the informal
representation of business interests through reverse clientelism.(40) Simply stated, part of the
private sector stayed put in a center, or even center-left, position within the statist consensus of
the past, while a growing part of the private sector shifted to the neoliberal right. The larger
traditional economic groups that were accustomed to receiving particularistic favors from the
state, as well as the newer or smaller firms that had good personal connections with the Herrera
or Lusinchi administrations, continued to lobby privately for preferential treatment by a large
state, because business as usual would help them compete with their rivals in the domestic
economy while protecting them from foreign competition. The Mendoza group, for example,
succeeded in placing one of its managers, Manuel Azpúrua, with the Lusinchi administration as
Minister of Finance. At the same time, a group of entrepreneurs friendly with Lusinchi's
personal secretary and mistress, Blanca Ibáñez, were showered with government contracts and
other state favors as long as Lusinchi was president. Also, an AD-affiliated businessman from
Zulia named Beto Finol parlayed his powdered milk company into a diversified business empire
with help from Lusinchi, whose campaigns he managed and helped fund.(41)
However, other firms--those that had never benefited from special government favor, or
that now found themselves without good political connections--reacted to the economic crisis by
organizing and calling for more transparent rules of the economic game. In 1984 a group of
businessmen, consultants, and academics founded the Grupo Roraima, which published a series
of studies critical of the politicized and statist environment in Venzuela and calling for thorough
economic and political liberalization.(42) Although this group survived only a few years, it spoke
eloquently for a growing part of the Venezuelan private sector, and some of its most active
directors and researchers--José Antonio Gil Yepes, Marcel Granier, Rogelio Pérez Perdomo, and
Elías Santana--went on to become well-known advocates for the market.
Most of the leaders of the leading parties wanted nothing to do with this economic
liberalism. They judged--correctly, it seems, for at least the next decade--that the voters would
punish any moves to the right, and probably also that a leaner state would provide them with
fewer opportunities to build and maintain support through clientelism, reverse or otherwise. But
because both AD and COPEI were pragmatic and heterogeneous, a small number of leaders in
each party found some of these new ideas attractive. In COPEI, General Secretary Eduardo
Fernández seems to have decided quietly to support moderate economic and political
liberalization before he emerged as COPEI's presidential candidate in the late 1980s. He was
not nominated because of his economic positions, however; in fact,he was virtually alone in his
programmatic stance within his party. During the campaign of 1987-88, VenEconomy reported
that "Fernández is the only COPEI leader of any weight calling for economic and political
change. Not even his closest allies within the party have joined him in these pledges."(43)
In Acción Democrática the situation was similar: most of the party leadership was quite
happy with Lusinchi's gradualist heterodoxy, but a few leaders quietly converted to a pro-market
orientation. Again, one of those converts became the party's presidential candidate for 1988--Carlos Andrés Pérez. And as in COPEI, the candidate was chosen for reasons that had nothing
to do with his positions on economic issues.(44) Pérez seems to have changed his mind to favor
the market only in the late 1980s, perhaps even after his nomination. As a respondent in October
1985 in my survey of AD leaders (for which he waived confidentiality), Pérez opposed subsidy
reductions, real wage cuts, import liberalization, privatization, tight money, elimination of price
controls, and elimination of barriers to foreign investment, while favoring exchange controls,
increased public investment, and export subsidies.(45) As president little more than two years
later, he did exactly the opposite of all these things. In the more center-left context of AD, it
would have been more costly to publicize such a conversion, so Carlos Andrés Pérez cleverly
allowed his supporters to believe whatever they wanted about his policies, by speaking only in
general terms about what he would do in office. Sophisticated voters, such as the editors of
VenEconomy, could not decide even six months before the election whether Pérez would be a
"populist" or a "developmentalist" if elected.(46) Unsophisticated voters probably expected that he
would somehow return Venezuela to the boom of the 1970s.
The Pérez Government
Once elected, Pérez appointed to his economic cabinet a team of radically pro-market
technocrats largely recruited from the Instituto de Estudios Superiores de Administración
(IESA). These ministers--among whom were Miguel Rodríguez, Moisés Naím, Ricardo
Hausmann, Gerver Torres, and Julián Villalba--became known as the "IESA Boys," by analogy
to the "Chicago Boys" of Pinochet's Chile. This team designed the shock "paquete" that Pérez
promised in his inaugural address in February 1989 and put into effect two weeks later. One
could attribute the president's conversion to the advice of this team, or to the influence of Pedro
Tinoco (a ringleader of the "Twelve Apostles") or the Cisneros economic group, or to pressure
from the IMF. But my own impression is that CAP became persuaded on his own to follow the
liberal path, learning from the mistakes of his first government and those following it, and from
the experience of his friend Felipe González in Spain. Then, consistent with his saying that "the
President must advise his advisers," which he was fond of repeating, he sought out advisers who
had the technical expertise to realize his goals.
Pérez's Gran Viraje introduced severe disruptions into the private sector. The policies had been developed and implemented with practically no business input, to minimize watering-down by lobbies. The old practitioners of reverse clientelism were therefore cut off from their accustomed access route to the state. The new entrepreneurs were better off because they were getting policies close to what they had wanted, but they suffered as well because the change came without warning and gave them little time to prepare for competition. In the short term, the paquete brought instability to the private sector, to the point of what Moisés Naím has called an "oligopolistic war":
The competition introduced by the reforms upset the delicate equilibrium between rival
groups, itself the result of years of intermittent wars, collusion and market-sharing
agreements. Whenever competition appeared, it seldom expressed itself through prices
or other marketing tactics, all of which had been inhibited by the interventionist policies
of the government. . . . Rivalries were essentially directed at gaining control of certain
strategically placed companies that would in turn ensure greater control, protection, or
influence over the actions of other companies contending in the same markets.(47)
These rivalries became quite nasty in the early 1990s as firms resorted to hostile takeovers, fake
press releases designed to drive down a rival's stock prices, industrial espionage, and
blackmail.(48)
Mass reaction to the paquete could not have been more negative: rioting and widespread looting broke out in all the major cities and lasted for three days. Brutal repression of the disturbances, now known as the Caracazo, resulted in hundreds of deaths. One of the important reasons for the violent rejection of the economic program was shock: few Venezuelans thought such drastic reforms were necessary. As Figure 2 shows, the number of people reporting that their economic situation was better than that of the year before reached its low point on Black Friday in 1983; but it increased fairly steadily during the Lusinchi government (ending January 1989). Elites were aware of terrible problems building due to the fiscal deficit, the overvalued Bolívar, and waning investment, but in the popular mind the rate of deterioration was slower than it had been at any time since 1978. And in the popular mind, the economic performance that followed the application of the shock program was far worse. In 1989, consumer prices rose 84.5 percent, GDP fell 7.8 percent, and per capita GDP declined 10 percent in less than a year;(49) it was by far the worst performance in anyone's memory. As Figure 2 shows, reports of personal economic decline hit a new low that year. As Kurt Weyland has argued, the fact that the shock program took effect when the crisis was not as deep as in Bolivia in 1985 or Argentina in 1989, and even seemed to be waning, taught ordinary Venezuelans that economic liberalization was unnecessary and bad, and reinforced their desire to return to comfortable statist policies of the past.(50)
This "lesson" learned at the mass level proved very difficult to unlearn. Opposition to
economic liberalization remained strong even in 1990-92, when the economy was making a
vigorous recovery. Inflation fell to the 30-40 percent range, production grew at an average
annual rate of 7.6 percent (9.7 percent in 1991, aided by the Gulf War windfall), and foreign
investment poured in. Venezuelans recognized some improvement in their personal economic
situations, as Figure 2 shows, but gave Pérez and his policies none of the credit for the
turnaround. I believe the reason for this is that the bad economic performance in 1989, and
generally in the preceding 15 years, became linked to two other powerful issues that emerged at
the same time.
The first of these issues was corruption, which was inherent in the reverse clientelism
that AD and COPEI had been practicing for years. All during the early 1990s the media were
filled with story after story about corrupt activities during the Lusinchi administration. It turned
out that RECADI had been used as a gigantic source of illegal enrichment. Its sole reason for
being was to allocate subsidized dollars among multitudes of claimants, a function made
necessary and possible by the policy of maintaining different exchange rates for different
purposes. Access to subsidized dollars became the easiest route to riches in the 1980s, and for
some firms it was crucial for solvency during the debt crisis. The Lusinchi government used
RECADI fraudulently and politically: friends of the government received cheap dollars easily,
even when they forged and falsified records to justify their claims. The subsidized currency
could then be safely invested abroad as a hedge against inflation, or sold on the black market at a
handsome profit, some of which found its way back into government and party officials' pockets
as kickbacks. RECADI was disbanded when Pérez unified exchange rates in 1989, but not
before billions of dollars had been funneled through it. This abuse of RECADI is the best
example of the magnitude of the economic interests at stake in reverse clientelism.
As far as the public was concerned, Venezuela's economic decline had little to do with
falling oil prices, rising interest rates, declining terms of trade, low productivity, or any of the
standard explanations; the principal reason was thought to be mismanagement and corruption.
Templeton reports that 69 percent of the population had heard of the RECADI scandals by 1992,
and 79 percent of these understood that corruption was involved.(51) When asked what single
factor was the principal cause of the crisis, more respondents (48 percent) chose "bad
government/corruption" than "economic factors" (37 percent), and when asked which factors
had "much" responsibility for the crisis, 86 percent--the largest number--chose corruption and 74
percent chose "bad administration of nation's resources."(52)
The second issue that became linked to bad economic performance was the rejection of
partidocracia. Even before the electoral defeat of AD and COPEI in 1993 there was clear
evidence of popular disillusionment with the two traditional parties. Abstention was one sign:
before 1978, it had never exceeded 10 percent; but in 1978 and 1983 it rose to 12 percent, and in
1988 it hit 18 percent. (In 1993 it soared to 41 percent.) Other evidence comes from public
opinion polls. When asked which party's positions were closest to their own, only 18 percent of
Venezuelans replied "none of the above" in 1988; but when the same question was asked in
September 1991, the proportion of non-sympathizers had nearly tripled, to 45 percent.(53) A
different survey in late 1991 asked what sort of person respondents would like to have as
president in four or five years; only 14 and 12 percent said they would like someone from AD or
COPEI, respectively, while three times as many said they would not like such a person.(54) David
Myers reports that in October 1988 (2 months before the election), 51 percent of respondents
claimed to have "little or no positive feeling" for AD, and 67 percent lacked sympathy for
COPEI; by June 1992, those percentages had risen to 71 and 75 percent, respectively.(55) The
disillusionment with parties holds up in comparative perspective as well: in the LatinBarometer
cross-national survey conducted in 1995, only 6 percent of Venezuelans had confidence in their
political parties. Confidence in parties was higher in Spain (32 percent), Uruguay (28 percent),
Mexico (23 percent), El Salvador (22 percent), Brazil (22 percent), Peru (17 percent), Bolivia
(14 percent), Colombia (12 percent), Chile (12 percent), and Ecuador (12 percent). Only in
Guatemala was it as low.(56)
This interpretation in which Venezuelans tended to equate economic crisis with
corruption and the abuses by the two main parties is even more directly confirmed by a study
conducted by Alfredo Keller. Based on survey research, Keller concluded that by 1993
Venezuelans were divided primarily by their pro- and anti-system inclinations. Half were
trapped in the clientelistic mindset of the past, expecting a strong leader to come along and
punish corrupt politicians and restore the good life to which all Venezuelans are entitled,
although preferably within a democratic framework. Another 15 percent were more radical,
totally alienated, and supporters of a coup or other complete break with the past, such as the
coup attempted by Lt. Col. Hugo Chávez Frías in February 1992. Only 35 percent were firmly
committed to change within the rules of the existing game, and 80 percent of those favored only
gradual change. A CSIS report summarizing Keller's findings observed that
four basic factors have become symbols of what must be changed in Venezuela. In order
of importance, these are 1) ex-President Pérez, 2) corruption, 3) the party hierarchy, or
cogollos [the inner circle of national party leaders in each party in whose hands
tremendous power was concentrated], and 4) the economic package. The more radically
placed a person is along the motivational continuum, the more simplistic his analysis of
these symbols. At the radical extreme, the four symbols became virtually synonymous. .
. . changing the social, political, and economic situation is a function of changing these
symbols; eliminate Carlos Andrés Pérez, corruption, the cogollos, and the economic
package, and the problems will have been eliminated as well.(57)
I have argued elsewhere that by the 1970s Venezuelan parties had become too strong:
their internal discipline was so rigid that they lost responsiveness to the rank and file, and their
obsession with penetrating and controlling other organizations in civil society blocked informal
channels of popular representation between elections.(58) These practices provided sufficient
reason to expect Venezuelans to become disillusioned with AD and COPEI. This claim was
never meant to imply that large numbers of Venezuelans subscribed to any sophisticated critique
of the parties' shortcomings with respect to high democratic ideals, although such a critique had
become virtually the conventional wisdom among the Venezuelan intellegentsia by the late
1980s. Rather, all that is intended is that the partidocracia I described caused or perpetuated
other problems, such as mismanagement, waste, corruption, inefficiency, unresponsiveness, and
overpromising and underdelivering, which saturated the environment in which all Venezuelans
lived, and were more directly responsible for the disenchantment that citizens increasingly felt.
The nature of the parties in Venezuela was largely responsible for the growing rejection of the
"establishment" in the 1990s even though many ordinary citizens were not conscious of the
ultimate source of the problem.
For the election of 1993, both AD and COPEI nominated presidential candidates
who possessed a clear commitment to the continuation of economic liberalization. Neither was
chosen because of that orientation, however, as factional struggles in Venezuelan governing
parties had become, since the late 1960s, personalistic nomination campaigns decided by guesses
about who was most likely to win the general election rather than by the attractiveness of the
candidates' ideas and platforms.(59) COPEI's Osvaldo Alvarez Paz won because of his record as
the effective and honest first elected governor of the large state of Zulia, and AD's Claudio
Fermín also had a regional base of support as the former mayor of Caracas. But during the
presidential campaign, neither made any secret of his economic positions, which delighted the
growing class of new, market-oriented business leaders. The potential for representation of
conservative interests through parties and elections looked promising.
These pro-market candidates, however, ran into a wall of public opposition. After
sharing upwards of 90 percent of the presidential vote since 1973, AD and COPEI's combined
share was halved to 46.3 percent in 1993. And for the first time since the 1960s it was a four-way race, because Andrés Velásquez, the former governor of Bolívar (home of Ciudad Guayana)
and leader of the new-unionist La Causa R, made a strong showing in the polls and ended up
nearly tying Fermín and Paz's totals. In this fragmented field the winner was Rafael Caldera,
who had left COPEI when it became clear that General Secretary Eduardo Fernández would not
allow him to win the nomination. As an independent candidate backed by his own vehicle
Convergencia Nacional, the Movimiento al Socialismo, and a coalition of 17 small parties
ranging from the right to the communists, Caldera staked out a clear center-left and anti-establishment (although not antidemocratic) position and was rewarded by the voters for it.
Representation of Conservative Interests Since 1994
The representation of conservative interests deteriorated during the Caldera government
(1994-1999) and with the election of Hugo Chávez Frías in December 1998 because neither the
more market-friendly business leaders nor those who hoped to protect themselves through
reverse clientelism got what they wanted. The more market-friendly leaders wanted clear
policies and liberal policies that they believed necessary for a healthy economy; but the
economic situation continued to get worse. A few of the would-be insiders had connections to
the Caldera government, but not most; and Chávez's election created a fear that all would be
frozen out.
Conservative interests were not well represented in the Caldera government itself. There
was some token representation because Caldera's first minister of finance was Julio Sosa, who
has long been identified with one of the largest and oldest family economic groups. However,
Sosa appeared to be a figurehead minister appointed because he was an old personal friend of
Caldera's who would be reassuring to investors, and he resigned after the first year. The chief
architect of Caldera's economic programs for the first 2 years was Luis Raúl Matos Azócar, a
strongly pro-union ideological social democrat who had been expelled from AD during the Pérez
administration. Caldera and Matos reestablished exchange controls, fixed certain prices, refused
to raise gasoline prices even when they had fallen to less than ten cents a gallon, halted
privatization, talked about rescheduling the foreign debt, and generally put the brakes on the
economic liberalization process. It would be hard to argue that they rolled back the market
reforms substantially, but their seven programs in 2 years were at least incoherent, which was
profoundly disturbing to business elites of all types. For example, when Caldera decreed a
bonus for private sector workers in March 1996, a vice president of FEDECAMARAS
complained that "with this isolated measure what the government is doing is throwing gasoline
on the inflationary fire."(60)
Conservative interests were not well represented in Congress, either. Both AD and
COPEI reacted to their electoral defeat by turning away from economic liberalization. This was
most dramatic in AD, where General Secretary Luis Alfaro Ucero led a purge of all of Fermín's
followers from the National Executive Committee and by January 1996 expelled 10,936 activists
at all levels who either broke with the party line in the 1995 regional elections, or were
suspected of being carlosandresistas.(61) In COPEI the change was less dramatic, but the party's
two most vocal advocates for the market, Eduardo Fernández and Osvaldo Alvarez Paz, were
marginalized within the national leadership, and nominal control of the party machinery passed
to the populist former president Luis Herrera and his protégé, Donald Ramírez. These internal
party changes meant that conservative interests, which had no close ties to the government, had
little influence with the major opposition parties, either.
In April 1996 the Caldera government adopted a neoliberal economic shock program.(62)
The indecisiveness appeared to end when the government freed all prices, slashed the gasoline
subsidy, raised the sales tax, radically devalued the currency, and let the exchange rate and
interest rates float. Perhaps because these measures were accompanied by various benefits and
wage increases, there was no repeat of the Caracazo, but the package was welcomed by the
World Bank, making it possible to resume negotiations on a new credit from the Bank. At the
same time, oil prices began to rise, yielding much-needed foreign currency, which the
government pledged to spend on reducing the foreign debt. But the success was brief. By the
end of 1997, the government had backed off on some of these policies in the face of strikes by
teachers and doctors, and a social security reform that was supposed to resolve conflicts over
unpaid (and unpayable) benefits mollified few. Worse yet, oil prices continued to fall, rendering
the Venezuelan state less and less able to pay for social programs, service its foreign debt,
balance the budget, and reduce inflation further.
The level of threat to conservative interests rose during 1998. At the beginning of the
year, Hugo Chávez Frías, the leader of the February 1992 coup attempt, reemerged as a viable
presidential candidate. By March he had captured the lead in the polls from Irene Sáez Conde,
who would have been a relatively reassuring pro-business, efficiency-minded independent. By
contrast, Chávez employed populist and extreme nationalist rhetoric, frequently lamenting the
poverty and hunger that so many Venezuelans were suffering. It was never completely clear
during the campaign whether he was truly on the left or just using a populist discourse.
Nevertheless, he did win the electoral backing of several left-of-center parties and the prospect
of his election did undermine business confidence. During 1998, the state failed to find buyers
for its aluminum companies, the economy contracted one percent, and the stock market fell 45
percent. But Chávez was doubly threatening to conservative interests: in addition to the prospect
of continuing state-centered center-left policies, his talk of eradicating the old corrupt party
establishment threatened to take away the safety net of reverse clientelism that the two parties
had built up over decades.
To recapitulate: after 1979, economic decline motivated some business leaders to wean
themselves from the old statist diet of subsidies, protection, and favors, and to move to the right.
Other business leaders were content to continue business as usual, but their numbers and
influence dwindled as the crisis deepened. The vast majority of ordinary citizens resisted the
shift to the right, and most of the leaders of the parties conformed to the majority view. When
two of the few party leaders who favored economic liberalization led their parties to historic
electoral defeats in 1993, the defenders of the economic and political status quo felt that their
strategy was vindicated, and marginalized the minority of promarket leaders and their followers.
During the Caldera government, then, the traditional practitioners of of reverse clientelism were
unsympathetic to the promarket firms, and not in a position to help the more traditional firms,
and the presidency was in the hands of an independent who was also unsympathetic to
neoliberalism, whose ability to do favors for traditional firms was constrained by the need to
protect his anti-corruption image, and whose incoherent policies were deepening the crisis,
hurting all firms alike.
With the election of Chávez, there were credible fears that these tendencies would be intensified. Business interests were left without any effective representation, formal or informal. Chávez may turn out to be no different from his predecessors: a president willing to cut deals and do business as usual, exchanging policy favors for material support. Indeed, in the last few months of his campaign, he took pains to reassure domestic and international business leaders that he was a reasonable man who welcomed foreign investment, and he succeeded in winning the grudging acquiescence of some. But if Chávez turns out to be as radical as he originally claimed to be, Venezuela may finally provide a true test of what happens when conservatives interests are poorly represented through both formal and informal channels.
Table 1: Venezuelan Cabinet Ministers with Business Ties | |||
President
and Years |
Position | Minister | Business Group |
Betancourt
1959-64 |
Finance
Agriculture |
Andrés Germán Otero
Héctor Hernández Carabaño |
Mendoza
Vollmer |
Caldera
1969-74 |
Finance
Finance |
Julio Sosa Rodríguez
Pedro Tinoco |
Sosa
Mendoza, Cisneros |
Pérez
1974-79 |
Federal District
Planning |
Carmelo Lauría Lesseur
Gumersindo Rodríguez |
Banco de Venezuela
Tinoco |
Herrera
1979-84 |
Finance | Julio Sosa Rodríguez | Sosa |
Lusinchi
1984-89 |
Finance | Manuel Azpurua Arreaza | Mendoza |
Pérez
1989-93 |
Chief of Staff | Carmelo Lauría Lesseur | Banco de Venezuela |
Caldera
1994-present |
Economy | Julio Sosa Rodríguez | Sosa |
Sources: Terry Lynn Karl, "The Political Economy of Petrodollars: Oil and Democracy in Venezuela,"
Ph.D. dissertation, Stanford University, 1982; Domingo Alberto Rangel, La oligarquía del dinero, 3rd
ed. (Caracas: Editorial Fuentes, 1972); Judith Ewell, Venezuela : A Century of Change (Stanford, Calif.:
Stanford UP, 1984); personal communication from José Molina Vega.
Endnotes
1. Robert R. Kaufman and Barbara Stallings, "The Political Economy of Latin American Populism," in Rudiger Dornbusch and Sebastian Edwards, eds., The Macroeconomics of Populism in Latin America (Chicago: U Chicago P, 1991), p. 20 [15-34].
2. Robert Dahl, Polyarchy: Participation and Opposition (New Haven, Conn.: Yale UP, 1971), pp. 36-40; Arend Lijphart, Democracy in Plural Societies: A Comparative Exploration (New Haven, Conn.: Yale UP, 1977), chapter 2; Michael Coppedge, "Instituciones y gobernabilidad democrática en América Latina," Síntesis 22 (julio-diciembre 1994): 61-88.
3. Terry Lynn Karl, "Petroleum and Political Pacts: The Transition to Democracy in Venezuela," in Guillermo O'Donnell, Phillippe Schmitter, and Laurence Whitehead, eds., Transitions from Authoritarian Rule: Latin America (Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins UP, 1986), p. 215 [196-219].
4. Guillermo O'Donnell and Phillippe C. Schmitter, Transitions from Authoritarian Rule: Tentative Conclusions about Uncertain Democracies (Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins UP, 1986), pp. 61-2. This is also the premise of Edward L. Gibson, Class and Conservative Parties: Argentina in Comparative Perspective (Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins UP, 1996).
5. When Rueschemeyer, Stephens, and Stephens argued that for the stabilization of Latin American democracies in the 1970s and 1980s, "the real key was political institutions, namely the existence of a party system affording protection to elite interests," they were wise not to specify what it was about party systems that would afford protection to elite interests. Dietrich Rueschemeyer, Evelyne Huber Stephens, and John D. Stephens, Capitalist Development and Democracy (Chicago: U Chicago P, 1992), p. 216.
6. Although Karl (p. 212) claims that "COPEI, in particular, represented traditional elite interests--a role it played with relative ease owing to its conservative Andean origins," the rest of her analysis emphasizes the informal relations between economic elites and both major parties.
7. Daniel Levine, Conflict and Political Change in Venezuela (Princeton, NJ: Princeton UP, 1976), chapter 3.
8. Karl, "Petroleum and Political Pacts," p. 212.
9. For example, according to one Copeyano historian, "UNE was a compact body, without currents or internal groups, that wanted for Venezuela the union of all Venezuelans; that pursued as its primordial goal the reconstruction of Venezuela as a spiritual and economic unit through the adoption of a healthy and firm nationalist ideal." José Elías Rivera Oviedo, Los socialcristianos en Venezuela (Caracas: Impresos Hermar, 1969), p. 52. These ideas evolved somewhat by the time COPEI drafted its founding "Manifiesto" in September 1946, but traces of organicism were still present: "For COPEI, . . . the class struggle is a fact derived from injustice and aggravated by frictions and demagoguery; a fact with antisocial implications that should be overcome by a complementary common effort from capital and labor, with the middle classes intervening as moderating forces, so that labor's rights are recognized and all contribute to the greatness of the nation and the general well-being." (Quoted in Rivera, Los socialcristianos en Venezuela, p. 80.)
10. El Universal, November 25, 1958. The announcement of this speech by URD Party Secretary Luis Miquelena was accompanied by a sketch of fascists beating students.
11. Michael Coppedge, "Strong Parties and Lame Ducks: A Study of the Quality and Stability of Venezuelan Democracy," Ph.D. dissertation, Yale University, 1998, p. 366. Naturally, the partisan views of COPEI's chief rivals should not be accepted uncritically.
12. Rivera, Los socialcristianos en Venezuela, pp. 64-65.
13. Ricardo Combellas, COPEI: Ideología y liderazgo (Caracas: Editorial Ariel, 1985), p. 114.
14. Rivera, Los socialcristianos en Venezuela, p. 18.
15. Rivera, Los socialcristianos en Venezuela, p. 49.
16. "Comunicado de COPEI ante la situación actual," December 3, 1948, quoted in Rivera, Los socialcristianos en Venezuela, p. 91.
17. Rivera, Los socialcristianos en Venezuela, p. 95.
18. The criteria used in this paper for "Right" and "Center-Right" are those I defined for a comparative study of Latin American party systems. Parties of the Right are: (1) parties that target heirs of the traditional elite of the 19th century without moderating their discourse to appeal to middle- or lower-class voters; (2) parties that employ a fascist or neo-fascist discourse; or (3) parties sponsored by a present or former military government, as long as they have a conservative (organicist, authoritarian, elitist, looking to the past) message and are not primarily personalist vehicles for particular authoritarian leaders. Parties of the Center-Right are parties that target middle- or lower-class voters in addition to elite voters by stressing cooperation with the private sector, public order, clean government, morality, or the priority of growth over distribution.
19. Robert J. Alexander, "Venezuela," in Robert J. Alexander, ed., Political Parties of the Americas: Canada, Latin American, and the West Indies, Vol. 2: Guadeloupe-Virgin Islands of the United States (Westport, Conn.: Greenwood Press, 1982), p. 725.
20. Michael Coppedge, "The Dynamic Diversity of Latin American Party Systems," Party Politics 4 (October 1998): table 3, p. 558.
21. Michael Coppedge, "Parties and Society in Mexico and Venezuela: Why Competition Matters," Comparative Politics 25:3 (April 1993): 253-74.
22. In my 1985 survey I asked 80 AD leaders where they would locate themselves on a 1-10 left-right scale. Their answers spanned the full range from 1 to 10, with about 40 percent at "5"--the most centrist position on the left--about 20 percent at a more leftist "3", and a small but significant number on the right half of the scale. See Michael Coppedge, Strong Parties and Lame Ducks: Presidential Partyarchy and Factionalism in Venezuela (Stanford, Calif.: Stanford UP, 1994), p. 76.
23. Obviously, the same practice is rampant in the United States, where it is called campaign finance.
24. It is probably impossible at this point to estimate accurately how widespread these practices are, but for documentation of specific cases of influence peddling, see the Diccionario de la corrupción en Venezuela (2 vols.) (Caracas: Editorial Capriles, 1990); Héctor Malavé Mata, Los extravíos del poder: euforia y crisis del populismo en Venezuela (Caracas: Ediciones de la Biblioteca y Consejo de Desarrollo Científico y Humanístico de la Universidad Central de Venezuela); and Terry Lynn Karl, "The Political Economy of Petrodollars: Oil and Democracy in Venezuela," Ph.D. dissertation, Stanford University, 1982. For insightful analyses of Venezuelan corruption, see Rogelio Pérez Perdomo and Ruth Capriles, eds., Corrupción y control: Una perspectiva comparada (Caracas: Ediciones IESA, 1991) and Moisés Naím and Antonio Francés, "The Venezuelan Private Sector: From Courting the State to Courting the Market," in Lous W. Gooman, Johanna Mendelson Forman, Moisés Naím, Joseph S. Tulchin, and Gary Bland, eds., Lessons of the Venezuelan Experience (Washington, D.C.: Woodrow Wilson Center Press, and Baltimore: Johns Hopkins UP, 1995), pp. 165-92.
25. Author interviews nos. 83 (January 18, 1985), 89 (July 10, 1985), and 78 (Dec. 11, 1985), with AD national deputies, all in Caracas.
26. Antonio Francés, "Abundancia, confusión y cambio: El ambiente en el que se desenvuelven las empresas y sus gerentes en Venezuela," in Moisés Naím, ed., Las empresas venezolanas: Su gerencia (Caracas: Ediciones IESA, 1989), pp. 103-104. [93-113].
27. Naím and Francés, "The Venezuelan Private Sector."
28. Karl, "The Political Economy of Petrodollars."
29. Hernando De Soto, The Other Path: The Invisible Revolution in the Third World (New York: Harper and Row, 1989), pp. 209-29.
30. For an analysis of "In" and "Out" factions in AD, see Coppedge, Strong Parties and Lame Ducks.
31. Domingo Alberto Rangel, La oligarquía del dinero, 3rd ed. (Caracas: Editorial Fuentes, 1972).
32. This table is based on my own reputational survey of a score of Venezuelanists and Venezuelan social scientists and consultants. I thank Víctor Hinojosa for research assistance in compiling a list of ministers in each cabinet and doing preliminary research on their business ties.
33. Karl, "The Political Economy of Petrodollars."
34. Coppedge, Strong Parties and Lame Ducks, chapter 6.
35. For the standard definition of societal corporatism, see Phillippe Schmitter, "Still the Century of Corporatism?" in Frederick B. Pike and Thomas Stritch, eds., The New Corporatism: Social-Political Structures in the Iberian World (Notre Dame, Ind.: University of Notre Dame Press, 1974), pp. 85-131. For applications of the corporatist model to Venezuela, see Jennifer L. McCoy, "Labor and the State in a Party-Mediated Democracy: Institutional Change in Venezuela," Latin American Research Review 24 (1989): 35-67; Ricardo Combellas, La democratización de la democracia (Caracas: IFEDEC, 1988), pp. 95-121; and Brian Crisp, "Limitations to Democracy in Developing Capitalist Societies: The Case of Venezuela," World Development 22 (October): 1491-1509.
36. For a more extended discussion of this point, see Coppedge, "Parties and Society in Mexico and Venezuela," pp. 260-61.
37. , For example, the Comisión sobre Costos, Precios, y Salarios (CONACOPRESA) lost the authority to make binding decisions soon after it began operations, was boycotted by the business representatives, and eventually was abandoned by the CTV as well. Moreover, many of its lower-level commissions never became operational. Eduardo Arroyo Talavera, Elecciones y negociaciones: Los límites de la democracia en Venezuela (Caracas: Fondo Editorial CONICIT/Pomaire, 1988), p. 227.
38. Naím and Francés, "The Venezuelan Private Sector," pp. 178 and 181.
39. Roderic Camp, Entrepreneurs and Politics in 20th-Century Mexico (New York: Oxford UP, 1989), chapters 7 and 8.
40. For an analysis of a strikingly similar process in Mexico, see Blanca Heredia, "Profits, Politics, and Size: The Political Transformation of Mexican Business," in Douglas Chalmers, M. de Souza, and Atilio Borón, eds., The Right and Democracy in Latin America (New York: Praeger, 1992), pp. 277-302.
41. Confidential interview no. 78, Caracas, December 11, 1985.
42. Grupo Roraima, Proposición al País (Caracas: n.p., 1984); Grupo Roraima, Más y mejor democracia (Caracas: Grupo Roraima, 1987). For information on other pro-market groups, see Francés and Naím, "The Venezuelan Private Sector," and Margaret Martín, "When the Model Ran Out: Institutions and Ideas in Transition in the Case of Venezuela 1979-1992," paper presented at the 1993 Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, The Washington Hilton, September 2-5, 1993.
43. The pledges referred to were summarized by VenEconomy as "redistributing political power, reorienting the economy around an externally oriented, supply-side model and growing private investment, industrial investment and exports, all within a climate of harmonization and relative liberalization of the economy." VenEconomy, The Economic Outlook for Venezuela, 1988-1993 (Caracas: Veneconomía S.R.L., June 1988), p. 25.
44. See chapter 6 of my Strong Parties and Lame Ducks, where I use the results of my survey of 80 top leaders of AD to compare the policy preferences of the factions backing different aspirants to the nomination. They were indistinguishable in terms of economic policy, and had much more to do with whether their members were insiders in the Lusinchi administration and whether they believed Pérez could win another general election.
45. It is of course possible that CAP was not telling me the truth. Even in 1985, however, he claimed to approve of the "Black Friday" devaluation and favored tax increases and a unified exchange rate, which could have been controversial positions better concealed.
46. VenEconomy, The Economic Outlook for Venezuela, pp. 25-27.
47. Moisés Naím, Paper Tigers and Minotaurs: The Politics of Venezuela's Economic Reforms (Washington, DC: The Carnegie Endowment for International Peace, 1993), p. 96.
48. Naím and Francés, pp. 177-78.
49. Source: Inter-American Development Bank.
50. Kurt Weyland, "Risk Taking in Latin American Economic Restructuring: Lessons from Prospect Theory," International Studies Quarterly 40 (1996): 197-99.
51. Templeton, "The Evolution of Popular Opinion," p. 91.
52. Ibid., p. 88-89. The other responses were: 59 for "world economic situation," 50 percent for "decline of moral values," 43 percent for "lack of leadership," and 30 for "egoism [selfishness]of Venezuelan people."
53. Alba Sánchez, "Poll Respondents Reject CAP, Support Caldera," translation of article in El Nacional, Jan. 26, 1992, p. D-2, in Foreign Broadcast Information Service--Latin America Report 92-037 (Feb. 25, 1992): 25-27.
54. Templeton, "The Evolution of Popular Opinion," p. 100. The ratios were more nearly even for various sorts of independent candidates.
55. David J. Myers, "Perceptions of a Stressed Democracy: Inevitable Decay or Foundation for Rebirth," in William Smith, Jennifer McCoy, Andrés Serbín, and Andrés Stambouli, eds., Venezuelan Democracy Under Stress (Coral Gables, Fla.: North-South Center and INVESP, 1995), p. 128. [107-37]
56. LatinBarometer data reported in La República (Lima, Perú), July 14, 1993, and reproduced in Jonathan Hartlyn, "Democracia en la actual América del sur: Convergencias y diversidades" Síntesis 22 (July-December 1994): 26-31 [17-51].
57. Technical Appendix to Robert Bottome, Rita Funaro, and Patricia Garip-Bertuol, "The 1993 Venezuelan Elections: Post-election Report," Center for Strategic and International Studies Latin American Election Study Series, Vol. XII, Study 1, Washington, DC, February 15, 1994, pp. 15-19; this summarizes Alfredo Keller, "El escenario socio-político venezolano," Consultores 21, S.A., May 1993.
58. Coppedge, Strong Parties and Lame Ducks.
59. Coppedge, Strong Parties and Lame Ducks, chapter six.
60. Aurelio Concheso, quoted in Humberto Márquez, "Venezuela: Sindicatos marcharán contra bonos a trabajadores," InterPress wire service report, March 8, 1996.
61. Humberto Márquez, "Venezuela: Acción Democrática cierra filas contra Pérez," InterPress wire service report, January 31, 1996.
62. Oddly enough, the architect of the program was Teodoro Petkoff, a MAS leader and former Communist guerrilla who became convinced that a drastic neoliberal program was the only way out, and who threatened to withdraw from the governing coalition if the government did not take decisive action. Caldera made Petkoff responsible for the package by appointing him Planning Minister and favoring his ideas over those of Finance Minister Matos Azócar. Like the advocates of market reforms in AD and COPEI, Petkoff was in the minority within his own party; but after Petkoff was given the most responsible government post ever won by a Masista, the party could not resist giving him a chance. If his plan worked, they reasoned, the party could rise on the coattails of a new Mitterand or Cardoso.